A-AIII SU RAND CORP SANTA MONICA CA /0g 5/3

Similar documents
Should the FCC continue to issue rules on media ownership? Or should the FCC stop regulating the ownership of media?

Before the Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C ) ) ) ) ) ) REPLY COMMENTS OF THE NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF BROADCASTERS

ACA Tunney Act Comments on United States v. Walt Disney Proposed Final Judgment

Before the Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, DC ) ) ) ) ) ) REPLY COMMENTS OF THE NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF BROADCASTERS

2015 Rate Change FAQs

Broadcasting Order CRTC

APPENDIX B. Standardized Television Disclosure Form INSTRUCTIONS FOR FCC 355 STANDARDIZED TELEVISION DISCLOSURE FORM

Considerations in Updating Broadcast Regulations for the Digital Era

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C

SIDELETTER ON LITERARY MATERIAL WRITTEN FOR PROGRAMS MADE FOR NEW MEDIA. As of February 13, 2008 Revised as of May 2, 2011

Appendix S: Franchising and Cable TV

Before the Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) REPLY COMMENTS OF THE NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF BROADCASTERS

BROADCASTING REFORM. Productivity Commission, Broadcasting Report No. 11, Aus Info, Canberra, Reviewed by Carolyn Lidgerwood.

RATE INCREASE FAQs. Can you tell me what one TV station/network costs? I am in a promotional package, are my rates changing now too?

Comments on Recommendations of ECTEL to the NTRC on Revised Draft Electronic Communications Bill

OECD COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 2001 Broadcasting Section

RATE INCREASE FAQs. Can you tell me what one TV station/network costs?

OECD COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 2001 Broadcasting Section

Ensure Changes to the Communications Act Protect Broadcast Viewers

Television. Topics for Today. What is a Network? How do Networks Create Value. The Relation Between the Studio and Television.

Submission to Inquiry into subscription television broadcasting services in South Africa. From Cape Town TV

TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF THE OFFER FROM. TRIBUNE TELEVISION COMPANY (COMPANY) WXIN/WTTV (STATION) Indianapolis, IN (DESIGNATED MARKET AREA)

PUBLIC NOTICE MEDIA BUREAU SEEKS COMMENT ON RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN THE VIDEO DESCRIPTION MARKETPLACE TO INFORM REPORT TO CONGRESS. MB Docket No.

Case No IV/M ABC / GENERALE DES EAUX / CANAL + / W.H. SMITH TV. REGULATION (EEC) No 4064/89 MERGER PROCEDURE

Before the Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C

AUSTRALIAN SUBSCRIPTION TELEVISION AND RADIO ASSOCIATION

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C COMMENTS OF GRAY TELEVISION, INC.

CLEAR CHANNEL BROADCASTING, INC. (COMPANY) WHP/WLYH (STATION) HARRISBURG, PA (MARKET)

Re: Public Notice CRTC : Diversity of Voices Proceeding

OECD COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 2001 Broadcasting Austria DSTI/ICCP/TISP(2000)6

Broadcasting Decision CRTC

May 12, In the Matter of 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review and Related Dockets (MB Docket No , MM Docket Nos , , )

Jersey Competition Regulatory Authority ( JCRA ) Decision M799/11 PUBLIC VERSION. Proposed Joint Venture. between. Scripps Networks Interactive Inc.

SENATE SUBCOMMITTEE ON COMMUNICATIONS

Department of Social Sciences. Economics Working Papers AGAIN GREENE. The Economics of the NAB Case. Brooks B. Hull and Carroll B.

TESTIMONY OF DR. MARK N. COOPER DIRECTOR OF RESEARCH MEDIA OWNERSHIP BEFORE THE SENATE COMMERCE COMMITTEE, WASHINGTON, D. C.

OECD COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 2001 Broadcasting Section

The NBCU Comcast Joint Venture

The NBCU-Comcast Joint Venture

NOW THEREFORE, in consideration of the mutual covenants and conditions herein contained, the parties hereto do hereby agree as follows:

DETERMINATION OF MERGER NOTIFICATION M/16/038- LIBERTY GLOBAL /UTV IRELAND

S Be it enacted by the Senate and House of Representatives of the United States of America in Congress assembled,

Title VI in an IP Video World

Before the. Federal Communications Commission. Washington, DC

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION WASHINGTON, DC 20554

1. Introduction. 2. Part A: Executive Summary

TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF THE OFFER FORM. Lin Television Corporation (LICENSEE) for the Station(s) WANE-TV (STATION(S)) broadcasting in

PYRAMID ( ) TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF THE OFFER FROM. Southeastern Ohio TV System (COMPANY) WHIZ-TV (STATION) Zanesville, OH (MARKET)

Broadcasting Decision CRTC

LINKS: Programming Disputes. Viacom Networks Negotiations. The Facts about Viacom Grande Agreement Renewal:

LOCAL TELEVISION STATIONS PROFILES AND TRENDS FOR 2014 AND BEYOND

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C

Policy proceeding on a group-based approach to the licensing of television services and on certain issues relating to conventional television

SUPERIOR COURT OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA FOR THE COUNTY OF LOS ANGELES ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) )

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE COMPETITIVE HARMS OF THE PROPOSED COMCAST-NBCU TRANSACTION* June 21, William P. Rogerson**

COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 1999

MAJOR COURT DECISIONS, 2009

CRS Report for Congress

14380/17 LK/np 1 DGG 3B

Metuchen Public Educational and Governmental (PEG) Television Station. Policies & Procedures

Post- Newsweek (COMPANY) WDIV (STATION) Detroit (MARKET) For the Distribution Broadc a s t Rights to the Sony Pictur e s Television Inc.

COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 1999

47 USC 534. NB: This unofficial compilation of the U.S. Code is current as of Jan. 4, 2012 (see

OECD COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 2001 Broadcasting Section

Fordham International Law Journal

The ins and outs of online video

David L. Cohen Executive Vice President. Comcast!GE Announcement Regarding NBC Universal

January 11, Re: Notice of Ex parte presentation in MB Docket No.07-57

Digital Television Transition in US

COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 1999

COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 1999

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, DC ) In the Matter of ) ) Sports Blackout Rules ) MB Docket No.

Before The FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, DC ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) )

LOCAL TELEVISION STATIONS: Maintaining an Important Presence in 2016 & Beyond. August Copyright All Rights Reserved.

TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF THE OFFER FORM. Meredith Corporation (COMPANY) WSMV Nashville, TN (MARKET)

Case 1:18-cv Document 1 Filed 06/27/18 Page 1 of 10 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK

Council of the European Union Brussels, 26 June 2017 (OR. en)

OECD COMMUNICATIONS OUTLOOK 2001 Broadcasting Section

SCREEN ACTORS GUILD AMERICAN FEDERATION OF TELEVISION AND RADIO ARTISTS

ARTICLE 1. When used in this Agreement, unless the context otherwise requires:

Before the Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C

Sinclair Broadcast Group Who We Are

NEW YORK CITY COLLEGE OF TECHNOLOGY The City University of New York. TCET Legal and Regulatory Issues in Telecommunications

[MB Docket Nos , ; MM Docket Nos , ; CS Docket Nos ,

Cable Rate Regulation Provisions

KANZ BROADBAND SUMMIT DIGITAL MEDIA OPPORTUNITIES DIGITAL CONTENT INITIATIVES Kim Dalton Director of Television ABC 3 November 2009

Before the FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Washington, D.C

SINCLAIR BROADCAST GROUP (COMPANY) See Rider A attached (STATION) See Rider A attached (DESIGNATED MARKET AREA)

THE FAIR MARKET VALUE

REQUEST FOR PROPOSALS AND TERMS OF REFERENCE

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case AT/2017/2020

2018 TELEVISION ANIMATION AGREEMENTS. Referendum Booklet

Written by İlay Yılmaz and Gönenç Gürkaynak, ELIG, Attorneys-at-Law

Credits. Guidance Note. Status of Guidance Note. Key Editorial Standards. Issued: 11 April 2011

Motion Picture, Video and Television Program Production, Post-Production and Distribution Activities

SEC ANALOG SPECTRUM RECOVERY: FIRM DEADLINE.

Coalition for Better Broadcasting

ATTACHMENT B DECLARATION OF ROBERT GESSNER

S4C Guidelines on Credits. 1 May 2015

Transcription:

A-AIII SU RAND CORP SANTA MONICA CA /0g 5/3 RVI W OF BARRY R. LITMAN. THI VERTICAL STRUCTURE OF THIE TeL.VI-ITC(U) ALL 81 S N les.n CLASSIFIED RA#/P4"50 ML END

00 REVIEW OF BARRY R. LITMAN, THE VERTICAL STRUCTURE OF THE TELEVISION BROADCASTING INDUSTRY: THE COALESCENCE OF POWER Stanley M. Besen July 1981 DTIC F L D18 32 Lt DISTRIBUTION STATENM. ± A Approved for public,,:,; 144 ~~0 P-6650

The Rand Paper Series Papers are issued by The Rand Corporation as a service to its professional staff. Their purpose is to facilitate the exchange of ideas among those who share the author's research interests; Papers are not reports prepared in fulfillment of Rand's contracts or grants. Views expressed in a Paper are the author's own, and are not necessarily shared by Rand or its research sponsors. The Rand Corporation Santa Monica, California 90406 *1~~~~~ I- ---- 1

Litman, Barry R., The Vertical Structure of the Television Broadcasting Industry: The Coalescence of Power, East Lansing, Michigan: Michigan State University (l979).* Barry Litman's bouk fits comfortably within the Federal Communications Commission's traditional view that the dominance of the television industry by the three major networks can be reduced by regulating their commercial practices. Although Litman recognizes that FCC spectrum allocation policies for broadcasting and policies affecting television systems that use alternative technologies have been responsible for the high degree of concentration in network television, he nevertheless remains sanguine about the prospects for improving industry performance by placing limits on contractual arrangements between the networks and other industry participants. Thus, as he examines the dealings of the networks with affiliated stations, with program producers, and with advertisers, he is continually searching for new rules that might lessen the role played by the three dominant networks and facilitate the growth of new program sources within the existing b- cadcast system. Throughout, Litman's concern is to establish that the power of ABC, CBS, and NBC stems from the manner in which they deal with their local distributors, their suppliers, and their customers and to find ways to reduce that power by regulating their practices. In 1980, the FCC Network Inquiry Special Staff (of which I was Co-Director between 1978 and 1980) presented to the Commission its own 1 analysis of network dominance. Like Litman, the Network Inquiry concluded that the source of the problem of network dominance could be found in Commission policies that had erected barriers to the formation This review is forthcoming in The Antitrust Bulletin.

2 of additional networks. Unlike Litman, however, it argued that little or nothing in the way of improved industry performance could be expected from extending traditional regulation of network behavior and that the result of doing so would be to force the industry increasingly to adopt inefficient commercial practices. Instead of urging the extension of regulation, therefore, it recommended that most existing rules be repealed. It concluded that only by removing barriers to the creation of new networks could the Commission enhance the ability of the industry to serve the viewing public. In this review, I draw upon the Final Report of the Network Inquiry Special Staff and its associated background reports and attempt to show why the Inquiry reached conclusions so at variance to Litman's and why the adoption of policy recommendations such as his are likely to do more harm than good. The Network Inquiry--the third major examination by the FCC of the question of network "dominance"--began in 1977 with a mandate to examine a wide array of network commercial practices involving dealings between the networks and their affiliates, on the one hand, and their program suppliers, on the other. In particular, the Commission asked whether existing practices limited the access of non-network program suppliers to the time of affiliated stations, whether these practices were in the public interest, and how existing regulations might be imp roved. Historically, the Commission has attempted to deal with network dominance within a system in which at most three nationwide outlets for programs could operate simultaneously. Since 35 percent of all households do not receive four commercial signals and many viewers

3 receive their fourth service over the inferior UHF band, the prospects for a fourth over-the-air advertiser-supported television network are severely limited. Rather than attempt to expand the number of networks that can operate simultaneously, either by radically revising its spectrum allocation plan, or by dismantling barriers to the growth of cable and pay television, however, the Commission has chosen to regulate network practices in an attempt to increase the number of competing entities within a system having a limited number of outlets. Thus, the Commission has established rules to prevent exclusive affiliations, has prevented networks from acquiring options on the time of their affiliates, and has placed constraints on the form of compensation paid to affiliates, all in an attempt to prevent the three major networks from acquiring a monopoly of their affiliates' time. More recently, the Commission has established rules designed to enhance the bargaining power, and hence the financial well-being, of the independent suppliers who produce the bulk of network entertainment programs. These rules prevent the networks from acquiring profit shares in independently-produced programs, or from becoming agents for independent suppliers in the syndication market, where programs are sold on a station-by-station basis. The rules preventing the networks from acquiring profit shares and syndication rights--the financial interest and syndication rules-- were accompanied by a rule that prevents the three major networks from supplying more than three hours of programming during the highlyprofitable prime time hours to their affiliates in the top 50 markets. The Prime Time Access Rule, the culmination of 25 years of FCC regulation I;r

4 of the television networks, was simultaneously to free affiliates from having to choose network prcgrams and to open a market to independent suppliers. This panoply of regulations proceeds from the premises that the networks are the adversaries of their affiliates and suppliers, that the networks have an unfair advantage in these relationships, and, most important, that a redressing of the imbalances will benefit not only affiliates and suppliers but the viewing public as well. However, each round of regulation has ended in frustration as the promised benefits failed to materialize, and suggestions for still more regulation have resulted. The Network Inquiry Special Staff concluded, on the basis of this experience, that only increases in the number of television oatlets and direct viewer payments could improve viewer welfare. The Inquiry argued, further, that banning a limited number of commercial practices was unlikely to reduce whatever market power the networks may possess, since alternative means are often available for the exercise of th:ct power. Finally, it held that regulation had led to the adoption of inefficient practices, to higher costs, and to poorer industry performance. Litman seems, at times, ti agree with much of this analysis, characterizing policies such as the ban on option time and the Prime Time Access Rule as failures. However, he attributes this to the fact "that marginal structural solutions will not bring about the desired results" and that "a radical restructuring of (the affiliation) contracts as a means of inducing greater competition among stations, encouraging entry of new programming, and increasing the quality of such programming" (pp. 48-49) is needed.2 His "radical restructuring" consists

5 essentially of preventing networks from offering an extensive lineup of programs to a large number of stations on a regular basis. Instead, each program would have to be offered station-by-station with sales to the highest bidder. It is, however, difficult to see how this policy recommendation is consistent with the author's conclusion that the Prime Time Access Rule (PTAR) has "failed" (p. 48), since the proposal amounts to little more than PTAR "writ large." Indeed, the only difference is that ABC, CBS, and NBC, the only program sources currently affected by the Rule, would be able to supply programs, although not through ongoing affiliation relationships. It is not clear how Litman expects viewers to be made better off since his proposal, like PTAR, would increase costs--by requiring the adoption of an inefficient distribution system--while leaving the number of broadcast outlets unchanged. Litman does argue that one benefit from his proposal will be to enhance the ability of existing independents to acquire "network" programs. But even assuming, unrealistically, that the policy leaves programming unaffected and that independents frequently do outbid affiliates, the benefits to viewers from having a program available on one channel rather than another seem non-existent. More realistically, viewers are likely to be made worse off, since the adoption of a more costly distribution system is likely to affect programming adversely. The principal benefit that Litman seems to envision from breaking ~3 up the network-affiliate relationship is that the profitability of independent stations will increase. The theme that the redistribution of industry profits away from the networks is a valid policy objective 7_4

6 appears elsewhere in Litman's book and has been an important element of FCC policy for many years. But it is arguable whether the distribution of industry piofits should be of concern to the Commission unless it affects the well-being of viewers. In this case, the result of redistributing profits is almost certainly to make viewers worse off, since distribution costs are increa' when station-by-station program sales replace the network-affiliate relationship. The experience under the Prime Time Access Rule provides ample evidence on this point. A similar concern with enhancing the profitability of independent program suppliers causes Litman to be critical of increased "in house" program production by the networks and of network acquisition of profit shares and syndication rights in independently produced programs. Litman accepts, with little reservation, the claims of program suppliers and the Department of Justice that the acquisition of these rights and the failure of network license fees to cover supplier production costs has rendered program supply unprofitable. Why suppliers continue to produce in the face of what appear to be consistent losses is a 4 puzzle to Litman. One reason he provides is that these losses are simply the price that producers pay for the pleasure of "being part of the 'Hollywood scene"' (p. 92),which should come as something of a shock to the shareholders of Gulf and Western (parent of Paramount), MCA (parent of Universal), and Transamerica (parent of United Artists). It is only with the greatest reluctance that Litman admits the possibility that the prospects of large returns in "off-network" syndication may bring forth supply even in the face of network license fees below production costs.

7 Litmar's analysis of program supply reveals most sharply two of the principal shortcomings of his entire book. First, without independent verification, he accepts almost any "fact" that seems critical of the actions of the networks. Thus, for example, he repeats the claim made by the Department of Justice that the license fee that will be paid in each year is determined at the beginning of the five-year option period common to most network entertainment program contracts. His "evidence" consists of DOJ exhibits detailing the terms of the initial contracts for two program series. But it is generally known in the industry that license fees are routinely renegotiated for subsequent years if a program is renewed after its first season. 5Unsurprisingly, the creative inputs of a successful series may acquire market power after the program appears on the network and in the resulting bilateral monopoly are usually able to negotiate higher fees. Second, Litman fails to appreciate how difficult it is to transfer profits from the networks to suppliers. The effect of a ban on the acquisition of syndication rights or profit shares, for example, can be offset by changes in other contract provisions, including a reduction 6 in the network license fee. Moreover, he fails to make clear how, even if profits could somehow be shifted, viewers would benefit. If Twentieth Century Fox makes larger profits from "MASH," is it really plausible that it will, as a result, choose to produce unprofitable programs? Litman cites evidence that "television tends to program according to the mass-appeal choices of the public and emphasizes uniformity rather than diversity" (p. 36), but fails to note that this results from the relatively small number of outlets and not from the existence of networks. Indeed, the evidence on program uniformity he reports

8 comes from the Prime Time Access period, when the networks do not provide programs! And although hie recognizes the efficiencies that the networks produce--"their ability to reduce costs to broadcasters (by simultaneous broadcasting), to national advertisers (by diminishing the number of transactions required), and to program suppliers (by central dealing and long-term commitments)"--he objects to network '#production of programs, ownership of stations, and various other related activities subsidiary to their major role in television" (p. 24). Little would be lost (or gained) if networks could not own stations or produce programs. Most of their local distributors are presently independently owned and, except for news and public affairs, most of their programs are produced by others. But much would be lost if Litman' s proposal were adopted and syndication replaced the network-affiliate relationship everywhere. And viewers would lose, as well, if the networks could not participate in the development of programs. I Litman insists on believing that no efficiencies result from ongoing network-affiliate relationships or from network involvement in program acquisition, and that they are engaged in by the networks solely to foreclose the entry of other program sources. These functions, which could easily be rationalized as leading to lower costs are, inevitably, seen by Litman as motivated solely by desire by the networks to control their environment and to increase their power over others. To be sure, the networks do wish to foreclose entry, but doing so is not without its costs and there are, thus, limits on the extent to which predatory behavior will be pursued. 7 At the same time, it is exceedingly difficult for the FCC to distinguish practices that promote efficiency from those that are

9//0 designed to thwart competitors, with the result that it is difficult for the Commission to invoke remedies that do more good than harm. Most important, however, only structural changes--increasing the number of outlets and providing for direct viewer payments--are likely to improve the fare available to viewers. As a result, the Network Inquiry Special Staff recommended that the FCC remove the last vestiges of regulatory-created barriers to entry, requiring ABC, CBS, and NBC to compete more vigorously with other networks for advertising, for programming, and, especially, for viewing.,! &

II FOOTNOTES /.deral Communications Commission, Network Inquiry Spec ial Staff, New Television Networks: Entry, Jurisdiction, Ownership and Regulation, 1980. -All page references are to Litman. 3One of the effects of PTAR has apparently been to increase the profits of independents, in part by permitting them to carry "offnetwork" reruns during the access period while restricting affiliates to the carriage of original syndicated programming. However, in citing evidence on the ability of independents to compete for audience during the access period period, Litman fails to note this restriction on affiliates' programming choices, contending that competition for programming during the access period is "on an equal footing" (p. 53). 4Litman cites as evidence the claim of the head of a "highly successful" production company, now the President of NBC, that the company "loses monev on all its shows" (p. 92). This has subsequently been confirmed by an extensive series of interviews with program suppliers and by a detailed examination of the contract files for a large number of network series (see Federal Communications Commission, Network Inquiry Special Staff, An Analysis of Television Program Production, Acquisition and Distribution, 1980), but it could have been discovered by Litman, as well. 6t 6One obvious question is why suppliers continue to ask for ineffective relief. One possible answer is that rules limiting the rights the networks can acquire differentially disadvantage new or small suppliers who have poorer access to alternative sources of financing than do the major motion picture studios. 7 Curiously, although Litman suggests in many places that the networks are vertically integrated in order to deter entry, he argues that the likelihood that integration into program production will be used to foreclose "seems very remote" (p. 13), and that "there is no concrete evidence on squeezes" resulting from station ownership (p. 14).

P 'U I p -. 1. 47 -. 9 I 4. A'... 0 f