Introduction to The Handbook of Economic Methodology

Similar documents
Methodology in a Pluralist Environment. Sheila C Dow. Published in Journal of Economic Methodology, 8(1): 33-40, Abstract

Normative and Positive Economics

Philip Kitcher and Gillian Barker, Philosophy of Science: A New Introduction, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2014, pp. 192

Kęstas Kirtiklis Vilnius University Not by Communication Alone: The Importance of Epistemology in the Field of Communication Theory.

TROUBLING QUALITATIVE INQUIRY: ACCOUNTS AS DATA, AND AS PRODUCTS

TEST BANK. Chapter 1 Historical Studies: Some Issues

Mixed Methods: In Search of a Paradigm

Introduction: Mills today

Seven remarks on artistic research. Per Zetterfalk Moving Image Production, Högskolan Dalarna, Falun, Sweden

(as methodology) are not always distinguished by Steward: he says,

The Shimer School Core Curriculum

Durham Research Online

These are some notes to give you some idea of the content of the lecture they are not exhaustive, nor always accurate! So read the referenced work.

Philosophy 345/Economics 319: The Philosophy and Methodology of Economics Spring 2014

8/28/2008. An instance of great change or alteration in affairs or in some particular thing. (1450)

observation and conceptual interpretation

Any attempt to revitalize the relationship between rhetoric and ethics is challenged

Mark Blaug on the Historiography of Economics

Metaphor and Method: How Not to Think about Constitutional Interpretation

What counts as a convincing scientific argument? Are the standards for such evaluation

PHILOSOPHY OF SOCIAL SCIENCE INTS 4522 Spring Jack Donnelly and Martin Rhodes -

Introduction to Recent Developments in Economic Methodology

Review of Maynard Keynes, An Economist's Biography by D. Moggridge

Review of Krzysztof Brzechczyn, Idealization XIII: Modeling in History

Part IV Social Science and Network Theory

UNIT SPECIFICATION FOR EXCHANGE AND STUDY ABROAD

GV958: Theory and Explanation in Political Science, Part I: Philosophy of Science (Han Dorussen)

Lecture 3 Kuhn s Methodology

By Maximus Monaheng Sefotho (PhD). 16 th June, 2015

Owen Barfield. Romanticism Comes of Age and Speaker s Meaning. The Barfield Press, 2007.

SUMMARY BOETHIUS AND THE PROBLEM OF UNIVERSALS

Environmental Ethics: From Theory to Practice

WHAT S LEFT OF HUMAN NATURE? A POST-ESSENTIALIST, PLURALIST AND INTERACTIVE ACCOUNT OF A CONTESTED CONCEPT. Maria Kronfeldner

The Nature of Time. Humberto R. Maturana. November 27, 1995.

Cultural Studies Prof. Dr. Liza Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Chapter 2. Critical Realism and Economics

IS SCIENCE PROGRESSIVE?

Sidestepping the holes of holism

Learning from the right neighbour: an interview with Jack Vromen

UNIT SPECIFICATION FOR EXCHANGE AND STUDY ABROAD

Part II. Rational Theories of Leisure. Karl Spracklen

Ralph K. Hawkins Bethel College Mishawaka, Indiana

Post-positivism. Nick J Fox

Introduction to The Elgar Companion to Economics and Philosophy

HPS 1653 / PHIL 1610 Introduction to the Philosophy of Science

The contribution of material culture studies to design

Capstone Design Project Sample

foucault s archaeology science and transformation David Webb

10/24/2016 RESEARCH METHODOLOGY Lecture 4: Research Paradigms Paradigm is E- mail Mobile

The Capitalist Unconscious Marx And Lacan

FOUNDATIONS OF ACADEMIC WRITING. Graduate Research School Writing Seminar 5 th February Dr Michael Azariadis

Writing an Honors Preface

SYLLABUSES FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS

What Can Experimental Philosophy Do? David Chalmers

Program General Structure

HISTORY ADMISSIONS TEST. Marking Scheme for the 2015 paper

Back to Basics: Appreciating Appreciative Inquiry as Not Normal Science

Interdepartmental Learning Outcomes

KINDS (NATURAL KINDS VS. HUMAN KINDS)

Relativism and the Social Construction of Science: Kuhn, Lakatos, Feyerabend

Rational Expectations

PHIL/HPS Philosophy of Science Fall 2014

Communication Studies Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:

The Debate on Research in the Arts

FORUM: QUALITATIVE SOCIAL RESEARCH SOZIALFORSCHUNG

The Epistolary Genre from the Renaissance Until Today. even though it is less popular than some other mainstream genres such as satire or saga, for

Theory or Theories? Based on: R.T. Craig (1999), Communication Theory as a field, Communication Theory, n. 2, May,

Please cite the published version in Human Studies, available at Springer via

Thomas Kuhn's "The Structure of Scientific Revolutions"

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

PROGRAMME SPECIFICATION FOR M.ST. IN FILM AESTHETICS. 1. Awarding institution/body University of Oxford. 2. Teaching institution University of Oxford

Four Characteristic Research Paradigms

HISTORY AND PHILOSOPHY OF SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY Vol. III - Philosophy of Economics - Adolfo García de la Sienra

Theory or Theories? Based on: R.T. Craig (1999), Communication Theory as a field, Communication Theory, n. 2, May,

Paradigm paradoxes and the processes of educational research: Using the theory of logical types to aid clarity.

Lawson on Veblen on Social Ontology

Q1. Name the texts that you studied for media texts and society s values this year.

GUIDELINES FOR AUTHORS

Three Meanings of Epistemic Rhetoric Barry Brummett SCA Convention, November, 1979

Hypatia, Volume 21, Number 3, Summer 2006, pp (Review) DOI: /hyp For additional information about this article

The topic of this Majors Seminar is Relativism how to formulate it, and how to evaluate arguments for and against it.

Introduction and Overview

In retrospect: The Structure of Scientific Revolutions

Dabney Townsend. Hume s Aesthetic Theory: Taste and Sentiment Timothy M. Costelloe Hume Studies Volume XXVIII, Number 1 (April, 2002)

M E M O. When the book is published, the University of Guelph will be acknowledged for their support (in the acknowledgements section of the book).

The Societal Impact of History Books: Citations, Reader Ratings, and the 'Altmetric' Value of Goodreads

Article Critique: Seeing Archives: Postmodernism and the Changing Intellectual Place of Archives

Special Issue Introduction: Coming to Terms in the Muddy Waters of Qualitative Inquiry in Communication Studies

The only uses of this work permitted are private study or research.

Readers and Writers in Ovid's Heroides

Phenomenology and Non-Conceptual Content

General Standards for Professional Baccalaureate Degrees in Music

Tradition in the Work of Shils and Polanyi: A Few Comments

Challenging the View That Science is Value Free

DOES THEOLOGY NEED A PARADIGM? LEARNING FROM ORGANIZATION SCIENCE AND MANAGEMENT RESEARCH


Davidson, Non-Ergodicity and Individuals

SYMPOSIUM ON MARSHALL'S TENDENCIES: 6 MARSHALL'S TENDENCIES: A REPLY 1

What is real about operational research?

Questions of aesthetics run through the contributions to this open issue of EnterText

Transcription:

Marquette University e-publications@marquette Economics Faculty Research and Publications Economics, Department of 1-1-1998 Introduction to The Handbook of Economic Methodology John B. Davis Marquette University, john.davis@marquette.edu Published version. "Introduction," in The Handbook of Economic Methodology. Eds. John B. Davis, D. Wade Hands, and Uskali Mäki. Cheltenham, ENG: Edward Elgar Publishing, 1998: xv-xviii. Publisher Link. 1998 Edward Elgar Publishing. Used with permission.

Introduction Our goal for the Handbook of Economic Methodology was to provide a detailed and comprehensive coverage of the field of economic methodology. Since economic methodology has only become a self-conscious research area during the last decade or two, some readers might wonder why we decided to edit such a volume at this particular time. Why not wait until the field has expanded and gained wider recognition? When we began the Handbook project five years ago, we believed there were at least two important reasons for proceeding with the project. These reasons say a great deal about what type of resource the Handbook ultimately became. To understand the first, it helps to have a little history of the development of the field of economic methodology. Economic methodology, at least late twentieth-century economic methodology, developed in part through a process of borrowing from the philosophy of science. Philosophers of science in the 1960s and 1970s were in the midst of abandoning the 'received view' inherited from logical positivism in the 1930s, and the excitement associated with names such as Karl Popper, Thomas Kuhn and Imre Lakatos soon transferred to a small contingent of historians of economic thought interested in the topic of theory appraisal. This historical literature in turn reinvigorated interest in a number of the classic topics in economic methodology, such as the debate between Robbins and Hutchison, Friedman's instrumentalism and Samuelson's operationalism, and it also served to establish economic methodology as a new field closely linked to the history of economic thought. For a number of years, economic methodology travelled along these lines, with continuing application of the postpositivist tradition within the philosophy of science to economics, and with further investigation into important methodological episodes in the history of economic thought back through the marginalist revolution to classical economics. Thus one reason for our feeling the Handbook of Economic Methodology would be useful at this particular time was that by the late 1980s economic methodologists had succeeded both in digesting recent developments from the philosophy of science, and in analysing many of the key methodological episodes in the history of economic thought. In effect, there existed a relatively well agreed upon body of metatheoretical research that had been produced during the immediately preceding period. However, there was another reason for the Handbook, and this second reason seems to be somewhat at odds with our first motivation. Simultaneous with the maturing of the field, there appeared a number of altogether new approaches to various topics in economic methodology, and these new approaches challenged the theory appraisal focus that had been economic methodologists' chief preoccupation during the previous decades. The rhetoric of economics and discourse analysis were the first to be recognized, but realism, the sociology of scientific knowledge and postmodernism also offered new strategies. Associated with these new, relatively autonomous, approaches came a range of new issues and topics that were distinct from the type of methodological debates historians of economic thought had already studied: selectionist arguments, hysteresis, holism, metaphor, reflexivity, microfoundations, experimental economics and folk psychology, to name but a few. Along with this development there was also entry into the field by a variety of individuals who had only modest links, or even no links, xv

xvi The handbook of economic methodology to the history of economic thought. Most prominently, practising philosophers took up the epistemological, logical, ethical and ontological problems associated with economics (a meeting ground that has been enhanced by the publication of the journal, Economics and Philosophy, starting in 1985). In addition, a number of practising economists and econometricians began to write about and comment on the methodology of economics, and more recently contributors from science studies have also added new perspectives. Thus in the last dozen or so years the field of economic methodology has expanded conceptually, in disciplinary focus and in terms of the total number of participants. From being a small and relatively selfcontained field examining well-known methodological disputes and using standard postpositivist philosophy of science, methodological discourse has now begun to expand in a variety of different directions and to integrate a wide range of new perspectives. We felt this more recent development was a very important reason for producing the Handbook of Economic Methodology at the present time. Since the field is apparently in a transitional phase, we thought it important to register the relative stability and state of consensus that has been achieved, so that future developments would have a common point of reference. Indeed, if the present proliferation of approaches and strategies continues unabated into the future, having an understanding of the various points of departure will be necessary for understanding what will undoubtedly be a very different, and more diverse, kind of methodological enterprise. Of course, the field may evolve in ways that make its origins of comparatively little interest. Against this are forces operating to establish economic methodology as a distinct field and these forces are likely to ensure some continuity of concern amidst the coming diversity of riches. The emergence of a second journal devoted explicitly to economic methodology - the Journal of Economic Methodology - is one indication of this development. Another is the increased acceptance of economic methodology as a legitimate mode of investigation within economics (and other fields, such as the philosophy of science). We hope that this Handbook becomes an additional force that sustains the perception of economic methodology as a distinct field with a series of antecedents permitting new developments into the future. Thus our second reason for producing the Handbook at the present time is to lay a foundation (or at least common ground) for the future evolution of the field. Our first reason was to characterize that common ground. How are these two rationales different in practical terms? The answer to this question is important for appreciating the structure of the Handbook and the different categories of entries it includes. It is one thing to set forth established understanding of economic methodology with entries on such topics as instrumentalism, Popper, Mill and marginalist controversy, but it is quite another thing to attempt to point beyond these standard topics with entries that focus on debates over more philosophical issues, wider intellectual themes and possible future research. Thus, in addition to ensuring that the Handbook has entries on as many as possible of the topics traditionally discussed by methodologists, we also sought to include entries on topics that lay behind these discussions, even if these issues are not always obvious to those engaged in the debate. To this end, we have included entries on such topics as probability, m!!ta.phor, aggregation, chaos and emergence. We certainly do not know where the interests of economic methodologists will take the field in the future, but these subjects do seem to have been involved in many of the standard long-standing discussions. In effect, such topics have been employed as foundational materials in the formation of the field of economic methodology. The Handbook thus contains two broad categories of entries: those that register where methodology has been, and those that signal where methodology may be going.

Introduction Cross-cutting this conceptual breakdown is another, four-way, classification ofthe volume's entries that has also helped shape the Handbook's final form. With no existing list of entries to which we might refer, we adopted the following four categories to guide the entry selection process. First, the Handbook includes biographical entries meant to introduce important economists, methodologists and (a few) philosophers. Most of these entries concern individuals from the history of economics and economic methodology, but some are individuals whose work is of more recent vintage. It should be noted that we intentionally did not include a number of living individuals who will undoubtedly figure in the future history of economic methodology. Partly this was on account of the difficulty of evaluating contemporaries and partly it was on account of the difficulty of knowing where to stop. There are many talented and accomplished individuals involved in economic methodology today, and many of them are contributors to this volume. Second, there are a number of entries that focus on issues in economics where methodological controversy has been central. By nature, these entries are mostly on subjects from the less recent history of economic thought, and thus are among the standard topics that one would consider in a course on economic methodology. As the present recedes into the past, there will be other important debates in economics with important methodological implications and overtones. These episodes would be added to the list of entries of future handbooks. Case studies on these episodes constitute an important area of research in economic methodology (as evidenced by the 1996 International Economic Association conference on methodological case studies) and we hope the entries included here will inspire more of this type of research. Third, there are many entries in this volume that emphasize the philosophical inheritance that economic methodology has received from the philosophy of science. These again, by and large, concern consensus subjects in the field, but they also reflect the fact that economic methodologists are no longer as dependent as they once were on the postpositivist philosophical framework. In addition, there are entries on a number of new areas of philosophical inquiry - both from general philosophy and from more recent philosophy of science - that represent possible future directions for methodological research. Selecting these entries was one of the more difficult tasks involved in editing the Handbook, since not only did we have to speculate about the possible significance of different philosophical views, but also we often found ourselves in disagreement about the importance of certain candidates. As a default strategy, a few such candidates were omitted. We leave it to future editors to evaluate the wisdom of our choices on this category of entries. Fourth, the Handbook includes entries on wider intellectual themes that have impinged on the work in economic methodology. These range from general movements in intellectual history to broad philosophical themes that pervade particular points of view in economics and economic methodology. In some instances, the distinction between well-established traditions and possible future developments is relatively easy to discern, since a number of the new programmes are known to most students of economic methodology, but in other cases we have tried to identify recurring themes that have only recently been recovered from the literature of the past. Because of the generality of many of these topics, it was often difficult to know exactly how to delineate entries, how, so to speak, to cut the literature at the relevant joints. Thus a number of the more general entries actually include subthemes that could have been entries themselves. Readers will need to search through them for many of the threads that are woven into larger fabrics. Finally, we should emphasize that the Handbook is aimed at a general readership that includes both those with a research interest in economic methodology and those concerned with learning the basics of the field. Moreover, we believe that the volume will appeal to those xvii

xviii The handbook of economic methodology interested in orthodox as well as heterodox approaches to economics. This volume, however, is not meant to provide a set of narrow tools that might function as a 'hands-on' or practical guide for the practice of economics. The day-to-day practice of economists enters only indirectly into the literature on the field of economic methodology and correspondingly into this volume. One last caveat: for a variety of reasons connected with the exigencies of the publication process, a number of the entries originally intended for the volume were not able to be included. We apologize to users of this volume for these omissions.